Freeman

ARTICLE

Men, Not Money, Will Overcome Poverty

MARCH 01, 1967 by WILLIAM HENRY CHAMBERLAIN

Mr. Chamberlin is a skilled observer and re­porter of economic and political conditions at home and abroad. In addition to writing a number of books, he has lectured widely and is a contributor to The Wall Street Journal and numerous magazines.

It is a common delusion that any problem, however deeply rooted in human psychological weakness­es and frailties, can be satisfac­torily solved by a sufficiently large appropriation of public funds. This is especially true as regards the so-called war on pov­erty. Not content with the huge sums already appropriated or in­dicated by the lavish spending programs of the 89th Congress, some ardent crusaders in this field want to go much farther, regardless of the effects on the shrinking value of the dollar or the fortunes of the majority of Americans who work for a living.

A group of men identified with "civil rights" and "labor" causes, including a few clergymen and economists, headed by A. Philip Randolph, president of the Broth­erhood of Sleeping Car Porters, recently came out with a proposal for the government to spend the modest sum of $185 billion for a drive to "end poverty in the next ten years," mostly by vastly in­creased contributions to existing items in the antipoverty program plus assuring a guaranteed annual wage, earned or not. This guar­anteed annual income, on top of lavish welfare outlays, would re­move the last serious incentive to work for the less skilled, while its cost would help to depress the standard of living of those who do work closer to the poverty level. Yet, the proposal also is favorably mentioned in a recent book by Walter W. Heller, chief of the Council of Economic Advisers in the Kennedy and Johnson admin­istrations.

Another ex-chief of the Council of Economic Advisers, Mr. Leon Keyserling, went along heartily with the $185 billion spending budget. Somewhat in the spirit of the dentist who assures his patient that the next turn of the drill in his molars will not hurt, he confidently asserts that the outlay of $185 billion will not hurt anyone because it will come out of the natural growth of na­tional income. This is the spirit of Dickens’ character, Micawber, ap­plied to finance. But, suppose the national income turns down in­stead of up; this has been known to happen.

A columnist who is noted for his freehanded attitude toward spending public funds, either for wars and expensive defense proj­ects or for huge schemes of ur­ban rehabilitation, warns that our cities are headed for a hopeless future unless tens of billions are somehow mobilized to rehabilitate them. The view is often expressed that the poor are being short­changed by the war in Vietnam, not because they are contributing much to its cost, but because they are missing the bigger handouts that would otherwise come their way. This is used as an argument for higher individual and cor­porate taxes, though such taxes would automatically dry up much of the consumer and investment spending which, together, are largely responsible for maintain­ing present jobs and creating new ones.

Before this hasty assumption that big government is both able and obligated to abolish poverty by writing more and bigger checks becomes firmly embedded in the national consciousness, some les­sons of experience about poverty, its causes and cures, should be considered.

The Relativity of Poverty

First of all, the word poverty is relative. What is considered poverty in the United States would be almost unimagined wealth to a large part of the population in Africa, Asia, and Latin America. One doesn’t find cars or television sets in the city slums of peasant villages of India, Nigeria, or Bra­zil; but cars and TV sets are by no means unusual possessions of wel­fare recipients in the United States. Pure water, electricity, and other public services are taken for granted in North America and Western Europe; not so, however, in culturally and economically re­tarded areas of the world.

Second, economic progress, even economic movement, has always been associated with economic sys­tems employing material incen­tives, such as differential pay for work of higher skill and responsi­bility. The nineteenth century Eu­ropean explorers who penetrated the interior of Africa found soci­eties of almost incredible back­wardness, unfamiliar even with such a simple device as the wheel, societies which had stagnated for centuries. Without condoning any sins of Western and Arab new­comers, especially in connection with the slave trade and some cases of gross exploitation of na­tive labor, it may fairly be said that every step of African prog­ress, in economic development, in education, in the building of a system of communications, was due to contact with the dynamic Western methods of civilization.

Even in communist-ruled states, the utopian ideal of paying every­one equally and sharing the prod­ucts of general labor equally has long been discarded as hopelessly unworkable. Wage and salary scales and perquisites of office are at least as rigidly graded, on an ascending and descending scale, in communist as in noncommunist states. The difference is that the industrial noncommunist states produce a much larger and more varied output of quality goods for everyday consumption, and are far ahead in agricultural productivity. Communists have tried in recent years to maintain inequalities in reward, and to mix some ele­ments of the market system with their planned economies, but their efforts have been fumbling and ineffective. Rigid centralized over­all planning, and the free market with its swift adjustment to changing consumer tastes and preferences, are like oil and water. They do not mix.

Now, if payment is unequal, some people obviously will be bet­ter off than others. Modern in­dustrial society has been described as affluent; and in many ways it is. Invention, technology, manage­ment organization along stream­lined efficiency lines, the use of computers and other up-to-date equipment, automation — all these and other modern developments, when free to function, make it possible to produce more goods for more people than the industrial system could turn out at any time in the past.

But no society, not even Ameri­ca’s, is sufficiently affluent to pro­vide for everyone the best of everything. There are, and prob­ably always will be, a few ex­tremely costly luxuries, yachts, mansions, jewelry valued in thou­sands of dollars, which are only within the reach of an economic top layer of the very rich. A large and enlarging middle class, in the economic sense of the term, a group that includes increasing numbers of manual workers, has access to a wide variety of minor luxuries and solid comforts.

Variability Among Individuals

Under any workable system of differential incentives there will always be a bottom tenth, or a bottom third, or whatever fraction may be chosen, that will be materially less well off than the aver­age. It is not only inequality of recompense that creates this situ­ation. It is the infinite inequality to be found in human character, human ability, human traits of all kinds.

Two men may start out with the same capital, the same amount of land, the same type of small manufacturing or trade establish­ment. The more competent of the two will forge ahead of the other. It is as simple and inevitable as water running downhill. One of the great illusions of modern times is that some impersonal force — government, society, or whatnot—is responsible for pov­erty and that this same force has the power and obligation to cure it.

The favored remedies are huge handouts of public funds or at­tempts to force up money wages out of line with market conditions by way of minimum wage laws or through the exactions of monopo­listic trade-union organizations. Even more drastic measures have been advocated, such as the nega­tive income tax, under which the state would arbitrarily raise the incomes of all families that had failed to achieve a certain income level.

What is overlooked is that pov­erty usually stems from personal inadequacies of one kind or anoth­er, which no amount of outside subsidies will correct. Poor hous­ing is often denounced as a breed­ing ground of crime, vice, and poverty, and is not to be defended on any ground. But here, the evil is easier to identify than the remedy. For, when modern, tax­payer-subsidized housing becomes available to slum dwellers, the re­sult all too often is quick degen­eration into a new slum, with elevators made unsafe by thugs, facilities damaged or destroyed by vandals. In other words, it is people as they are who make slums what they are.

Why Remedies Fail

Because money cannot buy those traits of individual character and initiative, many of the remedies for poverty which have been en­acted or proposed, from sincerely humanitarian motives, miss the mark or lead to results the very reverse of what is expected. Mini­mum wage legislation is the surest known device to stimulate unem­ployment, especially in the adoles­cent age group, where work would be a most desirable antidote to juvenile delinquency. It is no mere coincidence that unemploy­ment, especially among Negro teen-agers, has risen in a period of sharp boosts of the minimum wage level. No employer can pay help more than its economic worth and stay in business. Yet, that is what the minimum wage law in many cases requires.

Extravagant welfare payments are a potent cause of unemploy­ment, when they approach the wage levels paid for unskilled work. If the choice is between a life of subsidized idleness on relief or earning a few dollars a week more by putting in a day of regu­lar work, there are bound to be people who will opt for the check that comes without work.

International Ramifications

It is becoming an accepted dog­ma that the richer nations of North America and Europe owe an annual contribution in "foreign aid" to the poorer countries of the southern hemisphere. But experi­ence has shown that there are the same variations among nations as among people, with the more ener­getic managing to do without this aid or quickly outgrowing the need for it and others absorbing large handouts year after year without any visible improvement in their status.

Finland is a striking example of a country that proved able, after two unsuccessful wars, to pay a substantial indemnity to the So­viet Union and regain a fairly satisfactory standard of living without foreign subsidies from any source. Hong Kong, the Brit-ish colony on the southwest coast of China, is an even more vivid object lesson in the virtues and possibilities of self-help. Hong Kong is a picturesque rocky island with a small adjacent hinterland, both island and hinterland devoid of natural resources, apart from a fine natural harbor.

Commercial, banking, and ship­ping enterprises, attracted by the financial and political stability as­sociated with a government lim­ited primarily to police protection, transformed Hong Kong from a barren rock into one of the world’s great international ports. And since the communist take-over on the Chinese mainland, Hong Kong has experienced another transfor­mation. The city is bursting at the seams with industrious Chinese who voted against communism with their feet—by running away. And these Chinese, finding work at the lowest wages and under the hardest conditions preferable to their lot under communism, have enormously expanded Hong Kong’s trade and industry. The city has become the cosmopolitan shopping center of the Far East, with suits of the finest quality and expertly tailored available at short notice to the traveling for­eigner. And this recent significant expansion of Hong Kong was achieved without foreign help of any kind. It was just a matter of people with long experience in trade and handicrafts, denied a fair return for their labor at home, pulling up their sleeves and work­ing hard in a new environment of freedom.

Success and Failure

American aid to Western Eu­rope is now a matter of ancient history. Here it was mainly a mat­ter of starting again at full speed economies which had been stalled by war damage. And there are non-European countries — Israel and Taiwan are good examples—which have freed themselves from de­pendence on outside help. On the other hand, India, Indonesia, and the Congo, among other nations of Asia and Africa, furnish a depress­ing spectacle of inability to make both ends meet no matter how much foreign aid is poured into them.

The pioneer settlers of the United States received no foreign development aid and expected none. All they wanted from foreign powers was independence and from their own government to be let alone to go as far as their indus­try and ability would carry them. They were unconsciously putting into effect the only kind of anti-poverty campaign that is guar-anteed to produce results: intelligent, efficiently-directed, hard work.

The Human Factor in the Problem of Poverty

The human being, not the dol­lar, is at the heart of the problem of poverty, domestic and interna­tional. There are individuals who will succeed with little or no out­side help, because they seize every opportunity to help themselves. There are others who will founder no matter how many benevolent helping hands are extended to them, because the inner drive to move ahead in a competitive world is lacking.

Poverty will never be conquered, although it may be universalized, by putting on it a huge price tag, payable in public funds. Indeed, the whole idea of imposing on the productive part of the community an ever heavier burden of sup­porting the unproductive is fore­doomed to failure.

The best prospect—not of abol­ishing poverty, an unrealistic goal, but of diminishing and alleviating it—is to throw the fewest possible roadblocks in the way of thrift and industry. A given amount of capital, saved and invested in job-producing enterprises, will do far more to help the poor who can be helped than the same amount of capital seized by Federal, state, and local governments as taxes and distributed through bumbling bureaucratic agencies for supposed welfare projects. 

ASSOCIATED ISSUE

March 1967

comments powered by Disqus

EMAIL UPDATES

* indicates required

CURRENT ISSUE

November 2014

It's been 40 years since F. A. Hayek received his Nobel Prize. His insights, particularly on the distribution of knowledge and the impossibility of economic planning, remain hugely important today. In this issue, we look back on the influence of his work. Max Borders and Craig Biddle debate whether liberty must be defended from one absolute foundation, further reflections on Scottish secession, and how technology is already changing our world for the better--including how robots, despite the unease they cause, will only accelerate this process.
Download Free PDF

PAST ISSUES

SUBSCRIBE

RENEW YOUR SUBSCRIPTION