Freeman

PERSPECTIVE

Yale Brozen

A Man Who Helped Revive Widespread Acceptance of Free-Market Economics

JUNE 01, 1998 by SHELDON RICHMAN

Good economists do two things. First, they challenge people’s intuitions. (Such as: social order requires design; more people mean fewer resources; high market share indicates a lack of competition.) Then they make people say, “Oh, that’s simple; I should have thought of that.”

By that standard, Yale Brozen, a former member of the University of Chicago Graduate School of Business faculty and the FEE Board of Trustees, qualifies as a very good economist.

Brozen died March 4 at the age of 80. The obituary in the San Diego Union Tribune paid him the highest compliment an economist can be paid. It said his “persuasive arguments and tenacious scholarship helped revive widespread acceptance of free-market economics.” That aptly describes Yale Brozen. He was part of that revival precisely because he could do what too few economists can: he could write for the non-economist. He did it, among many venues, in the pages of The Freeman. In December 1966 he wrote his first Freeman article, “Welfare Without the Welfare State.” Then in September 1967 he contributed “Rule by Markets Versus Rule by Men.” That article was followed by “The Untruth of the Obvious” in June 1968, “The Attack on Concentration” in January 1979, and “The Mythology of Energy” in July 1979.

We are pleased to reprint “The Attack on Concentration” in the present issue. Some of Brozen’s most important work was in the area of economics called “industrial organization.” Theoretically and empirically, he showed that a high market share for a dominant firm, absent government barriers to entry, was consistent with vigorous competition. With the Department of Justice [sic] persecuting Microsoft for having too many customers for its computer operating system, Brozen’s article is as important as ever. Clearly, the attorneys in the department need to learn some economics.

Brozen began teaching business economics in 1957 at the University of Chicago, where he was a colleague of future Nobel laureates F. A. Hayek, Milton Friedman, and George Stigler. He was an editorial adviser to New Individualist Review, an important early journal of libertarian thought edited by Ralph Raico and Ronald Hamowy at the university. Brozen contributed two articles to NIR, “Wage Rates, Minimum Wage Laws, and Unemployment” (Spring 1966) and “The Revival of Traditional Liberalism” (Spring 1965).

In the latter he wrote, “A discussion of the revival of liberalism should begin with a description of what it is—particularly since our latter-day reactionaries have stolen the name. They have stolen the label for a good reason: it stands for the opposite of what they propose. . . . Literally, liberalism meant to liberalize or liberate—to make free—to permit men to do or say whatever they wished. Of course, there was a constraint implied in this. No man could do anything which affected the liberty of others. . . . The classical liberal was and is opposed to all forms of tyranny.”

Yale Brozen will be missed.

* * *

David Henderson leads off the issue with a professional and personal appreciation of Yale Brozen, who did not have to be a household name to make a real impact on economic thinking.

Thomas DiLorenzo goes back to the nineteenth century to demonstrate Brozen’s point that in a free market, a dominant firm, or “trust,” signifies competition, falling prices, and expanded production. The implications for the antitrust laws and the Microsoft case are monumental.

Leonard Read, FEE’s founder, liked to remind people that economics is not about numbers but about human action, choices, and values—which makes it a branch of moral philosophy. We reprint his classic article on the subject in our year-long observance of the one hundredth anniversary of his birth.

Civil society is the latest fad interest among academic writers who see a conflict between individual freedom and the “social good.” Drawing on the wisdom of an earlier writer, Juliana Geran Pilon believes that resolving the alleged conflict lies in the insight that benevolence is a form of self-love.

Voltaire, that joyous figure of the Enlightenment, visited London early in the eighteenth century. Wandering into the Stock Exchange, writes Wendy McElroy, he beheld the key to England’s peace and prosperity.

There is a place on earth where there is no central government, where law arises from custom based on respect for the individual, and where trade today flourishes. Spencer Heath MacCallum will be our tour guide.

Contemplating how the bureaucrats use statistics to justify their meddlesome work, John Wenders sees numbers as the key to government mischief-making. Since they conceal more than reveal, they are the perfect cover for intervention.

Lots of good theory has been penned to demonstrate that government should not build and operate public-works projects, such as railroads and canals. Burton Folsom makes the same point via history, using Stevens T. Mason, a governor of Michigan in the nineteenth century, as an example of a well-intentioned government official who learned that politics and entrepreneurship don’t mix.

In “The Pursuit of Happiness,” guest columnist Edward Younkins finds a surprising number of movies that portray business activity in a good light. Take this article with you next time you head for the video store. Doug Bandow talks about the budget surplus. Lawrence Reed counsels: In Government Don’t You Trust. Dwight Lee looks at the role of incentives in economics. And Mark Skousen traces the intellectual odyssey of a prominent English economic historian.

Our book-review section examines the source of wealth, gun control, the connection between progress and freedom, environmental concerns, free trade, and subsidies to workers.

—Sheldon Richman

ASSOCIATED ISSUE

June 1998

ABOUT

SHELDON RICHMAN

Sheldon Richman is the former editor of The Freeman and TheFreemanOnline.org, and a contributor to The Concise Encyclopedia of Economics. He is the author of Separating School and State: How to Liberate America's Families.

comments powered by Disqus

EMAIL UPDATES

* indicates required

CURRENT ISSUE

December 2014

Unfortunately, educating people about phenomena that are counterintuitive, not-so-easy to remember, and suggest our individual lack of human control (for starters) can seem like an uphill battle in the war of ideas. So we sally forth into a kind of wilderness, an economic fairyland. We are myth busters in a world where people crave myths more than reality. Why do they so readily embrace untruth? Primarily because the immediate costs of doing so are so low and the psychic benefits are so high.
Download Free PDF

PAST ISSUES

SUBSCRIBE

RENEW YOUR SUBSCRIPTION

Essential Works from FEE

Economics in One Lesson (full text)

By HENRY HAZLITT

The full text of Hazlitt's famed primer on economic principles: read this first!


By FREDERIC BASTIAT

Frederic Bastiat's timeless defense of liberty for all. Once read and understood, nothing ever looks the same.


By F. A. HAYEK

There can be little doubt that man owes some of his greatest suc­cesses in the past to the fact that he has not been able to control so­cial life.


By JEFFREY A. TUCKER

Leonard Read took the lessons of entrepreneurship with him when he started his ideological venture.


By LEONARD E. READ

No one knows how to make a pencil: Leonard Read's classic (Audio, HTML, and PDF)