Freeman

ARTICLE

The Cheapest Means of Payment

MAY 01, 1984 by JOSEPH S. FULDA

Joseph Fulda is Assistant Professor of Computer Science at Hofstra University and resides in Manhattan.

We were sitting in my mentor’s study discussing the vagaries of the teaching profession when he remarked: “You know, Joseph, we must pay for everything in life, and generally the cheapest way is with money.” I chuckled, but was struck with the insight. And on the way home later, I found myself asking “Why?”

In this short piece I would answer that question. Free market economists define money not as that which is “legal tender, for all debts public and private”—i.e., what government accepts or obliges others to accept as payment—but rather as the most marketable commodity—i.e., what people most willingly accept as payment. It is true, to be sure, that our money—unbacked legal tender as it is—is also most marketable; we make the distinction, however, because the answer to our question depends on the defining quality of money, not on any incidental attributes.

Money is so marketable in part because it has been so marketable and the recipient is thus assured that he will be able to use it as a means of exchange for goods and services of direct use. (This is a reason why once-backed money can so long survive by government fiat.) What is really desired, of course, are goods and services of direct use. In a specialized economy such as ours—or any modern economy—the chances are quite small that one person’s surplus goods or services will be precisely those needed by his trading partner. To pay his partner in exchange with these, then, would necessitate his giving more. For what he offers is neither of direct use nor easily marketable (or as easily marketable as money) in exchange for items of direct use. The matter is made even worse when the payment will be with such intangibles as favors or other private services for which there is almost no general market; for knowing that situation the trading partner is likely to ask for far more than he otherwise would. He will ask, as is customary, for whatever the market will bear. And the market will bear much when the supply is almost unlimited and the demand almost nil.

Economic analysis reveals that payment in kind will have two components: (1) the market worth of whatever is received in exchange, and (2) the market cost of transferring the items received into items of direct use or, alternatively, the price the recipient is able to charge for re ceiving something of lesser utility in exchange for something of greater utility. This second component merely confirms that before an exchange both parties must believe that they will be better off. This does not mean, however, that whoever offered payment in kind—perhaps in intangibles—is actually better off later, nor does it mean that he would not have been still better off had he offered a commodity which is more marketable—money. Money, after all, is the cheapest means of payment.

ASSOCIATED ISSUE

May 1984

comments powered by Disqus

EMAIL UPDATES

* indicates required

CURRENT ISSUE

December 2014

Unfortunately, educating people about phenomena that are counterintuitive, not-so-easy to remember, and suggest our individual lack of human control (for starters) can seem like an uphill battle in the war of ideas. So we sally forth into a kind of wilderness, an economic fairyland. We are myth busters in a world where people crave myths more than reality. Why do they so readily embrace untruth? Primarily because the immediate costs of doing so are so low and the psychic benefits are so high.
Download Free PDF

PAST ISSUES

SUBSCRIBE

RENEW YOUR SUBSCRIPTION

Essential Works from FEE

Economics in One Lesson (full text)

By HENRY HAZLITT

The full text of Hazlitt's famed primer on economic principles: read this first!


By FREDERIC BASTIAT

Frederic Bastiat's timeless defense of liberty for all. Once read and understood, nothing ever looks the same.


By F. A. HAYEK

There can be little doubt that man owes some of his greatest suc­cesses in the past to the fact that he has not been able to control so­cial life.


By JEFFREY A. TUCKER

Leonard Read took the lessons of entrepreneurship with him when he started his ideological venture.


By LEONARD E. READ

No one knows how to make a pencil: Leonard Read's classic (Audio, HTML, and PDF)