Freeman

BOOK REVIEW

Rolling Back the Market: Economic Dogma and Political Choice by Peter Self

Another Critique of the Free-Market System

DECEMBER 01, 2001 by MICHAEL D. MALLINGER

Filed Under : Capitalism, Free Markets, F. A. Hayek

St. Martin’s Press · 2000 · 265 pages · $26.00 paperback

Reviewed by Michael D. Mallinger

Critiques of the market system are a dime a dozen. Authors of these critiques typically choose to gloss over most of the theory underlying classical economics and classical-liberal political philosophy. However, what sets Peter Self apart is his willingness to examine how the writings of modern scholars like F. A. Hayek and James Buchanan relate to the original views of political economy developed by Adam Smith, John Stuart Mill, and others.

Although Self is able to uncover some of the bridge between contemporary and historical supporters of economic liberty, he is unwilling to explain how the academic ideas of classical economists have led Public Choice scholars to question the efficiency of the political allocation of resources in an economy.

Self’s chapter on philosophy begins on a positive note. He characterizes the origin of political liberalism this way: “Liberalism is basically an individualist tradition. It celebrates the rights and responsibilities of individuals. Its strong attachment to individual freedom stresses the right of individuals to choose and make their own lives and to take responsibility for the outcomes. It also endorses equality in the sense of the equal moral worth of all individuals and their entitlement to respect and consideration. As a child of the Enlightenment, liberalism has always had strong belief in the value of human reason and in the possibility of human progress.”

From this he explains how the writings of Smith and John Locke enabled individuals to progress from a social system based on personal status to a system based on contractual relations made possible by the spread of market-based principles. He notes that Mill formally laid down the framework of how market economies function, but claims his unhappiness with the outcomes of those economies led him to advocate a guaranteed basic income for all workers. Thus, like Jan Narveson, Self claims that Mill’s work led to a split between “negative” liberals who accept market-based outcomes and “positive” liberals who believe that states should enable individuals to maintain their personal autonomy, but must also provide them with a “minimum of resources and opportunities.”

Self cites Hayek and Herbert Spencer as the key scholars who sounded the alarm on the growth of government. He rightfully credits Hayek for anticipating the tyranny of fascist and communist totalitarian regimes; he also credits Hayek with issuing “a comprehensive warning of the destruction of liberty, which results from the complete concentration of political and economic power in the same set of rulers.” As a result, he states that separating and dispersing political authority among autonomous individuals is necessary for liberty to persevere.

Unfortunately, although Self emphasizes the links from Smith and Mill to Hayek and Buchanan, he is unable to comprehend the logical consistency among all of their arguments. He asserts that individuals who lived in the era when the classical economists wrote had strong moral standards regarding their personal and family lives that are largely absent today. That may be true, but it doesn’t weaken the case for laissez faire. In addition, he claims that the growth of capitalism occurred to serve a specific moral mission—to lift the poor out of misery and exploitation. Had Self better understood Hayek, he would know that spontaneous orders do not grow to serve particular purposes.

While Self’s analysis of the philosophy of liberalism provides some insight into how markets produce wealth, his discussion of various policy issues leaves much to be desired. His section on the failure of the price mechanism to take account of environmental costs reads like a summary of Earth in the Balance rather than serious scholarship. His critique of free trade repeats much of the mindless rhetoric used by the various groups that demonstrated against the World Trade Organization in Seattle. His case against Gordon Tullock’s theory of rent-seeking rests on the assertion that certain interest groups seek to remedy social or environmental problems that “transcend the market” rather than pursuing their own selfish interests. But there is far too much evidence that idealistic groups are eventually captured by those who use them for personal gain to take Self’s argument seriously.

Overall, Self’s examination of the philosophy underlying classical economics and classical liberalism is more fair and enlightening than one would expect in a critique of the market system. Unfortunately, much of the rest of the book is gravely flawed.

Michael Mallinger is a research associate at the Competitive Enterprise Institute.

ASSOCIATED ISSUE

December 2001

comments powered by Disqus

EMAIL UPDATES

* indicates required

CURRENT ISSUE

December 2014

Unfortunately, educating people about phenomena that are counterintuitive, not-so-easy to remember, and suggest our individual lack of human control (for starters) can seem like an uphill battle in the war of ideas. So we sally forth into a kind of wilderness, an economic fairyland. We are myth busters in a world where people crave myths more than reality. Why do they so readily embrace untruth? Primarily because the immediate costs of doing so are so low and the psychic benefits are so high.
Download Free PDF

PAST ISSUES

SUBSCRIBE

RENEW YOUR SUBSCRIPTION

Essential Works from FEE

Economics in One Lesson (full text)

By HENRY HAZLITT

The full text of Hazlitt's famed primer on economic principles: read this first!


By FREDERIC BASTIAT

Frederic Bastiat's timeless defense of liberty for all. Once read and understood, nothing ever looks the same.


By F. A. HAYEK

There can be little doubt that man owes some of his greatest suc­cesses in the past to the fact that he has not been able to control so­cial life.


By JEFFREY A. TUCKER

Leonard Read took the lessons of entrepreneurship with him when he started his ideological venture.


By LEONARD E. READ

No one knows how to make a pencil: Leonard Read's classic (Audio, HTML, and PDF)