Freeman

BOOK REVIEW

Economics of a Pure Gold Standard

A Standout from Mainstream Treatments of Alternative Monetary Systems

DECEMBER 01, 1996 by ROBERT BATEMARCO

Early in his marriage, Ludwig von Mises told his wife that despite writing prolifically about money he was never likely to earn a great deal of it. Mark Skousen makes the case in Austrian Economics for Investors (subtitled Ludwig von Mises Goes to Wall Street) that the ideas of Mises and his confreres do indeed have money-making potential. Showing the importance of subjective elements in forecasting, the impact of government policies on economic growth, the behavior of different types of industries over the course of the business cycle, and the role of gold as an inflation hedge are but a few ways Skousen sees Austrian insights as helping the reader put his capital to work.

While Austrian Economics for Investors touches upon the topic of gold, the role as money of the metal Keynes once dismissed as a barbarous relic is discussed thoroughly in Skousen’s Economics of a Pure Gold Standard, just re-issued by the Foundation for Economic Education. It goes one better than showing the reader how 100 percent gold reserve banking might work, by showing how it actually did work in seventeenth-century Amsterdam, Hamburg, and Venice. From there, it provides some unfamiliar details to the familiar story of how practices once considered criminal came to be venerable standards. Specifically, the author explains how money’s fungibility (i.e., particular pieces of money not being specifically identifiable) led British courts to construe bank deposits as loans, culminating in the 1833 decision of Pitts v. Glegg, which conferred legal status and has not since been challenged to fractional reserve banking.

A thorough rendering of the views of hard money advocates, from the Founding Fathers through the Jacksonians, the British currency school, and Murray Rothbard, serves as prologue to a survey of the issues involved in a pure specie standard, including what the unit of account should be, whether to allow for private provision of coinage, and the role of banks under such a system. Free banking as an alternative to a pure gold standard is discussed here as well. Skousen also covers several perennial critiques of a 100 percent specie system including its purported costliness and violation of the sanctity of private contracts. In so doing, he shows the ease with which hard money proponents turn each of these arguments to the gold standard’s advantage.

In the first case, they show how the cost of labor and capital expended to mine additional gold is dwarfed by the inflation, business cycles, bank failures, and hidden tax burden incurred under any regime with less than 100 percent reserves. In the second, their arguments hinge on the prohibition of fraud being a defense of private contracts rather than their violation. To the extent that depositors are informed about the banks’ use of their money, this case is less than airtight. A stronger argument, conspicuous by its absence, is that any money creation which reduces the reserve ratio is really an act of counterfeiting.

While the economics of the gold standard is clearly this book’s long suit, it stands out from mainstream treatments of these issues by dealing forthrightly with some of the ethical and philosophical issues of alternative monetary systems. Yet, the book ends with the sobering realization that the insights of the 100 percent gold standard advocates are necessary but not sufficient for breathing life into such a system. Or, as the author puts it, the 100 percent specie standard, advantageous as it may be portrayed, can be instituted only through drastic reforms and economic disruptions. It may have theoretical beauty, but it lacks pedestrian attributes. Lovers of liberty can only hope that Skousen is as wrong about the prospects of returning to sound money as he believed Mises to be about the money-making implications of Austrian economics.

ASSOCIATED ISSUE

December 1996

ABOUT

ROBERT BATEMARCO

Robert Batemarco is a former economics professor who is currently a vice president at a New York marketing research consultancy.

comments powered by Disqus

EMAIL UPDATES

* indicates required

CURRENT ISSUE

December 2014

Unfortunately, educating people about phenomena that are counterintuitive, not-so-easy to remember, and suggest our individual lack of human control (for starters) can seem like an uphill battle in the war of ideas. So we sally forth into a kind of wilderness, an economic fairyland. We are myth busters in a world where people crave myths more than reality. Why do they so readily embrace untruth? Primarily because the immediate costs of doing so are so low and the psychic benefits are so high.
Download Free PDF

PAST ISSUES

SUBSCRIBE

RENEW YOUR SUBSCRIPTION

Essential Works from FEE

Economics in One Lesson (full text)

By HENRY HAZLITT

The full text of Hazlitt's famed primer on economic principles: read this first!


By FREDERIC BASTIAT

Frederic Bastiat's timeless defense of liberty for all. Once read and understood, nothing ever looks the same.


By F. A. HAYEK

There can be little doubt that man owes some of his greatest suc­cesses in the past to the fact that he has not been able to control so­cial life.


By JEFFREY A. TUCKER

Leonard Read took the lessons of entrepreneurship with him when he started his ideological venture.


By LEONARD E. READ

No one knows how to make a pencil: Leonard Read's classic (Audio, HTML, and PDF)