Freeman

ARTICLE

Auto-Safety Standards

AUGUST 01, 1967 by MILTON FRIEDMAN

Now that the furor over car safety has subsided, it is instructive to consider some little-noticed as­pects of the Federal legislation it produced.

1. Cost. The recently issued safety standards will raise the cost and hence the price of new cars. According to some estimates, consumers will pay about $1 bil­lion a year extra.

Suppose Congress had been asked to appropriate this sum for the identical safety equipment, raising the money by a special excise tax on automobiles. Would Congress have enacted this pro­posal as readily as it enacted the safety legislation? Yet, the two are identical except in form.

2. Delegation of power to tax. Congress has been jealous of its prerogative to impose taxes. Time and again it has rejected proposals that the President be granted dis­cretion to alter tax rates. Yet, in this case, as in other similar cases, Congress has delegated to an ad­ministrative official near-absolute power to decide how large a tax to impose.

3. Failure to compare alterna­tives. The basic issue before Con­gress was safety, not requiring automobile manufacturers to build their cars in specified ways. Yet, so far as 1 know, there was no discussion whether $1 billion a year would contribute more to safety if spent in this way than if spent in other ways — on im­proved highways, or driver edu­cation, or better enforcement of speed limits, or more intensive investigation of causes of auto accidents.

4. Who will set the standards? The National Traffic Safety Agen­cy has already been criticized for yielding to the demands of manufacturers in drawing up its final safety standards for 1968 cars. Mr. William Stieglitz re­signed as consultant to the agency on roughly these grounds. Such complaints will be even more jus­tified in the future — though the complaints themselves may be­come less shrill.

How else can it work out? Safety standards are a peripheral matter to most car owners. A Ralph Nader may get them or the politicians aroused enough to pass a law; but once the law is passed, the consumers will return to som­nolence, from which only an oc­casional scandal will reawaken them. The car manufacturers are in a very different position. They have billions at stake. They will assign some of their best talent full-time to keep tabs on the standards. And who else has the expertise? Sooner or later they will dominate the agency — as, despite well-publicized tiffs, rail­roads and truckers have domi­nated the ICC; radio and TV net­works, the FCC; physicians, state medical licensure boards; and so on.

5. Effect on competition. Several small specialty-car manufacturers have already complained that com­pliance with the new safety re­quirements would put them out of business — the 1931 Ford that one company replicates has less glass in total in its windshields than the windshield wiper standards require the wipers to clear! No doubt, special exemptions will be granted to these companies. But how shall we ever know about the innovations that might have been made, or the companies that might have been established, without this additional handicap?

The effect on foreign producers will be even more important. Any extra cost will be more of a burden on them than on U.S. producers because they sell a much smaller fraction of their output in the U.S. Beyond this, it will become clear to the agency — staffed as it must be by men trained in the U.S. industry and in daily touch with it — that our cars are really safer and that the way to promote safety is to require foreign cars to meet American specifications.

The result will be a sheltered market for U.S. producers — and higher costs to U.S. consumers that have little to do with safety requirements.

6. The effect on safety. To begin with, the standards may well make cars safer. But, as administrative rigor mortis sets in, they will soon slow up product improvement, so that a decade from now cars may well be less safe. Reduced com­petition will reinforce this ten­dency. In addition, the higher price of new cars will raise the average age of cars on the road.

7. An oft-told tale. Time and again, laws passed to protect the consumer have ended up by re­stricting competition and so do­ing the consumer far more harm than good. Is it too much to hope that one of these days we shall learn this lesson before we enact a new law rather than after?

Copyright Newsweek, Inc., June 5, 1967. Re­printed by permission. 

ASSOCIATED ISSUE

August 1967

comments powered by Disqus

EMAIL UPDATES

* indicates required

CURRENT ISSUE

December 2014

Unfortunately, educating people about phenomena that are counterintuitive, not-so-easy to remember, and suggest our individual lack of human control (for starters) can seem like an uphill battle in the war of ideas. So we sally forth into a kind of wilderness, an economic fairyland. We are myth busters in a world where people crave myths more than reality. Why do they so readily embrace untruth? Primarily because the immediate costs of doing so are so low and the psychic benefits are so high.
Download Free PDF

PAST ISSUES

SUBSCRIBE

RENEW YOUR SUBSCRIPTION

Essential Works from FEE

Economics in One Lesson (full text)

By HENRY HAZLITT

The full text of Hazlitt's famed primer on economic principles: read this first!


By FREDERIC BASTIAT

Frederic Bastiat's timeless defense of liberty for all. Once read and understood, nothing ever looks the same.


By F. A. HAYEK

There can be little doubt that man owes some of his greatest suc­cesses in the past to the fact that he has not been able to control so­cial life.


By JEFFREY A. TUCKER

Leonard Read took the lessons of entrepreneurship with him when he started his ideological venture.


By LEONARD E. READ

No one knows how to make a pencil: Leonard Read's classic (Audio, HTML, and PDF)