Freeman

ARTICLE

A Reviewers Notebook: The Case for Conservatism

JANUARY 01, 1992 by JOHN CHAMBERLAIN

In his introduction to Francis Graham Wilson’s little book on The Case for Conservatism (Transaction Publishers, 78 pages, $21.95 cloth) Russell Kirk notes that Lionel Trilling could write in 1949 that “liberalism is not only the dominant but even the sole intellectual tradition.” But no sooner had Trilling made his remark than “the literary and philosophical adversaries of liberal dogmata rose up in numbers.”

Francis Wilson, described by Kirk as “an austere-looking, dryly humorous gentleman and scholar” who had retired from the University of Illinois to live at the Cosmos Club in Washington, was more than happy to be among those who proved Trilling’s lack of prescience. But Wilson does not pretend to be a perfectionist. He is quite aware that the major political parties often echo each other, and that elections are won by narrow margins that shift from time to time with pressure group changes. He thinks that conservatism is a philosophy of social evolution “in which certain lasting values are defended within the framework of the tension of political conflict.” When given values are at stake, a conservative may even become a revolutionary—though not as a Marxian, with the theory of class struggle, might assert. Wilson thinks class war ideas are abominable.

We have to live, says Wilson, with the results of past revolutions. Conservatism “is a spirit of politics rather than a fixed program . . . . Intellectual conservatism has at its command the whole range of philosophy and science that the centuries of Western civilization have provided.”

This identification of conservatism with Western Civilization itself may be regarded by today’s liberals as thievery. But between what is known as “old-fashioned liberalism” and Wilson’s conservatism there is little difference.

What are Wilson’s own descriptions of the common characteristics of the conservative mind in the West? He lists five that seem to him of special importance. First, he says, “conservative thought has attempted to find a pattern in history that may give some clues as to the possible and impossible in politics. Second, conservatives have generally been somewhat distrustful of human nature, viewing it as a mixture of the rational and irrational. Third, the conservative has in general believed there is a moral order in the universe in which man participates and from which he can derive canons or principles of political judgment. Fourth, conservative thought has accepted as sound politics the idea that government should be limited in its power and that such limitations should run on behalf of individuals and groups. And fifth, the conservative mind has defended the institution of property, I think, long before the rise of modern capitalism. . . . Certainly the defense of property is a more steady principle than the defense of particular arrangements by which goods are manufactured and distributed.”

The moral order, says Wilson, “is one of the oldest products of Western society, for it begins in the Greek distinction between nature and convention; it flowers in the concept of natural law in Roman civil law and in Christian philosophy . . . . any democracy that has long survived has believed that government is responsible to the community, but that responsibility must be exercised with restraint and moderation, under the rule of law.”

The preconditions of majority rule have been stated in the Bill of Rights, primarily the rights to life, liberty, and property. That, after all, is the case for conservatism.

ASSOCIATED ISSUE

January 1992

comments powered by Disqus

EMAIL UPDATES

* indicates required

CURRENT ISSUE

December 2014

Unfortunately, educating people about phenomena that are counterintuitive, not-so-easy to remember, and suggest our individual lack of human control (for starters) can seem like an uphill battle in the war of ideas. So we sally forth into a kind of wilderness, an economic fairyland. We are myth busters in a world where people crave myths more than reality. Why do they so readily embrace untruth? Primarily because the immediate costs of doing so are so low and the psychic benefits are so high.
Download Free PDF

PAST ISSUES

SUBSCRIBE

RENEW YOUR SUBSCRIPTION

Essential Works from FEE

Economics in One Lesson (full text)

By HENRY HAZLITT

The full text of Hazlitt's famed primer on economic principles: read this first!


By FREDERIC BASTIAT

Frederic Bastiat's timeless defense of liberty for all. Once read and understood, nothing ever looks the same.


By F. A. HAYEK

There can be little doubt that man owes some of his greatest suc­cesses in the past to the fact that he has not been able to control so­cial life.


By JEFFREY A. TUCKER

Leonard Read took the lessons of entrepreneurship with him when he started his ideological venture.


By LEONARD E. READ

No one knows how to make a pencil: Leonard Read's classic (Audio, HTML, and PDF)